Wednesday, 14 May 2014

The Student Loan Issue Looks Clear Enough At First Glance:

By Ester Brown


Students are incurring out sized student debt, and they are defaulting on that debt and endangering their ability to get future credit. The approaches to student loan debt assortment are fraught with difficulties, including improper recovery tactics and informational asymmetry affecting repayment alternatives.

But the current public policy dialogs miss essential problems that lead to the debt mess, leading to proffered options that also miss their mark.

Start with these key facts about student loans:

The reported student debt loans represent averages, yet the amounts owed can differ dramatically from student to student.

Another Viewpoint on Loans

The right level of default for a school's grads and student loan debt depends heavily on mission and an institution's students, compose Jacob Gross and Nicholas Hillman.

A lot of the debatable student loans are held by individuals who left school before graduation, meaning they've incurred "debt without diploma." Default data is distorted by this reality, producing their indicia of school quality misleading. The cost of instruction is not necessarily commensurate with the caliber of the instruction received, meaning some students pay more and get less, and we do not have an adequate system for measuring educational quality apart from accreditation, which is a greatly flawed process.

Finally, students and their own families are woefully unaware of the myriad repayment alternatives, and thus forgo existing advantages or are taken advantage of by loan services. This occurs because we d-e-link dialogs of "front-end" costs of higher education from "back end" repayment choices and opportunities; students and their own families are scared off by the front end without knowing that there is purposeful back end aid.

Given these facts, it becomes clearer why some of the current government reform suggestions are misguided. Two illustrations:

First, evaluating colleges on a rating system based on the earning levels of their graduates assumes the overwhelming majority of students graduate and that the employment chosen will be high-paying. But we know that not to be true, and for good reason: some students proudly enter public service or other low-paying but publicly beneficial employment.

In addition, we understand that these from high income families have better networking chances, given family links. Yes, some universities offer levels with small or no worth, but the means to fix student loan indebtedness doesn't rest on a gains brink.

Second, seeking at loan default charges as a measure of the achievement of a faculty misses that numerous faculties welcome students from low income quartiles, although obviously many are working to improve these figures, and these students have less collegiate success -- understandably.

Not that many years before, private lenders mastered both the student lending and home mortgage markets. This created clear parallels between lending in these two spheres. Lenders over-priced for hazard, provided monies to borrowers who were not credit worthy, and had loan products with troubling attributes like considerable front-end fees, high default interest rates and aggressive debt collection practices.

In both markets, there was an embedded premise: genuine estate values would continue to grow and well-paying employment opportunities would be ample for faculty graduates.

Then several things happened. The federal government took over the student loan market, cutting out the private lender as the middleman on government loans on both the front and back end. The economy took a nosedive that led to diminished home values and lower employment opportunities. And, when the proverbial bubble burst in the home lending markets, lenders sought to foreclose, only to find that their collateral had diminished in value.

For student loans, the bubble has not burst and, despite hyperbole to the contrary, it is unlikely to burst because the government -- not the private sector -- is the lender. Indeed, this market is intentionally not focused on credit worthiness; if anything, it awards more dollars to those who have weak credit, specifically to enable educational opportunity.

And while the rates of interest charged on student loans, the dimensions of Pell Grants along with the developing default charges can be debated by Congress, it's highly unlikely the student loan marketplace will soon be privatized anytime soon.

But, for the document, there are already hints that private lenders and venture capitalists have reentered or are prepared to reenter this market, for better or worse. And should the us government's financial aid offerings are or become less favorable than those in the open marketplace, we are going to visit a resurrection of private lending offered to students and their loved ones. One caveat: history tells us that the threats of the private student loan market are large.

You will find things that can and ought to be done to increase the government-run student-lending market to encourage our most vulnerable learners to pursue higher education at institutions which will serve them nicely. Here are five timely and doable suggestions worth considering now:

(1) Lower the interest rates on government-issued sponsored Stafford loans. The government is making significant profit on student loans, and we must encourage quality, market-sensitive, fiscally wise borrowing, most particularly among vulnerable students. Student loans to our most financially insecure students should remain without heed to creditworthiness (the worthiness of the academic institution is stage 2). Otherwise, we will be left with educational opportunity available only for the affluent.

Improve the accreditation process so that creditors assess more thoughtfully and fairly the institutions they govern, whether that accreditation is regional or national. Currently, there are vastly too many idiosyncrasies in the process, including favoritism, violation of due process and fair dealing, and questionable competency of some of the creditors. And the government has not been sufficiently proactive in recognizing creditors, despite clear authority to do so.

Simplify (as was done successfully with the FAFSA) the repayment options. There are too many options and too many opportunities for students to err in their selection. We know that income-based repayment is under-utilized, and students become ostriches rather than unraveling and working through the options actually available. Mandated exit interviews are not a "teachable moment" for this information; we need to inform students more smartly. Consideration should be given to information at the time repayment kicks in --- usually six months post-graduation.

(4) Steer school and universities to work with post-graduation default charges (and re-payment choices) by creating plans where they (the academic institutions) pro-actively reach out with their alumnae to handle repayment choices, an initiative we shall be attempting on our own campus. Progress in institutional default rates could be structured to empower raised institutional access to national monies for work study or SEOG, the greater the progress, the greater the growth.

The suggestion, then, is contrary to the proffered government approach: taking away advantages.

(5) Produce a brand new financial product for parents/guardians/family members/friends who wish to borrow to assist their children (or those whom they are raising or supporting even if maybe not biological or measure children) in progressing through higher education, replacing the present Parent Plus Loan.

We have to stop shouting concerning the shared catastrophe and see exactly how we can actually help students and their families get higher education instead of making them run for the proverbial hills.




About the Author:



No comments:

Post a Comment